跳至主要内容

Local Taxation, Private-Public Consumption Complementarity, and the Optimal Number of Jurisdictions

Read full paper at:
http://www.scirp.org/journal/PaperInformation.aspx?PaperID=52095#.VIVBx2fHRK0

Viewing local finances under the approach to private-public consumption complementarity, we conclude that foot voting and tax competition become extinct when the (capital) tax structure across jurisdictions is the one forging close ties between the burgher and his/her jurisdiction. The attachment of the burgher to the local public goods offered and to the local business activity prevents labor and capital mobility. The optimal number of jurisdictions is that which is conducive to the adoption of that local taxation that fosters such an attachment; taxation made possible by capitalizing upon private-public consumption complementarity. The intuitive appeal of this result is then contemplated within the broader framework of fiscal policymaking accommodative of citizen heterogeneity. In view of complementarity, there appears to be scope for decentralized treatment of citizen preferences via the localities, leaving the treatment of endowment differences to the central government.
Cite this paper
Soldatos, G. (2014) Local Taxation, Private-Public Consumption Complementarity, and the Optimal Number of Jurisdictions. Theoretical Economics Letters, 4, 815-820. doi: 10.4236/tel.2014.49103
 

[1] Tiebout, C. (1956) A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64, 416-424.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/257839
[2] Hoyt, W. (1991) Property Taxation, Nash Equilibrium and Market Power. Journal of Urban Economics, 30, 123-131. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(91)90049-D
[3] Perroni, C. and Scharf, K.A. (2001) Tiebout with Politics: Capital Tax Competition and Constitutional Choices. Review of Economic Studies, 68, 133-154. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1467-937X.00163
[4] Fiorito, R. and Kollintzas, T. (2004) Public Goods, Merit Goods, and the Relation between Private and Government Consumption. European Economic Review, 48, 1367-1398.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2004.01.004
[5] Linnemann, L. (2006) The Effect of Government Spending on Private Consumption: A Puzzle? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 38, 1715-1735. http://dx.doi.org/10.1353/mcb.2006.0094
[6] Bouakez, H. and Rebei, N. (2007) Why Does Private Consumption Rise after a Government Spending Shock? Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne d’Economique, 40, 954-979.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1365-2966.2007.00438.x
[7] Ganelli, G. and Tervala, J. (2009) Can Government Spending Increase Private Consumption? The Role of Complementarity. Economics Letters, 103, 5-7. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2009.01.007
[8] Ogura, S. and Yohe, G. (1977) The Complementarity of Public and Private Capital and the Optimal Rate of Return to Government Investment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 91, 651-666.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1885887
[9] Bucci, A. and Del Bo, C. (2009) On the Interaction between Public Investment and Private Capital in Economic Growth. UNIMI—Research Papers in Economics, Business, and Statistics, Universitá degli Studi di Milano Unimi-1092, Universitá degli Studi di Milano, Milano.
[10] Figuières, C., Prieur, F. and Tidball, M. (2013) Public Infrastructure, Non-Cooperative Investments, and Endogenous Growth. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne d’Economique, 46, 587-610. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/caje.12024
[11] Eichner, T. and Runkel, M. (2012) Interjurisdictional Spillovers, Decentralized Policymaking, and the Elasticity of Capital Supply. American Economic Review, 102, 2349-2357.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.102.5.2349
[12] Gahvari, F. and Micheletto, L. (2012) Monetary Policy and Redistribution: What Can or Cannot Be Neutralized with Mirrleesian Taxes. Uppsala Center for Fiscal Studies Working Paper 2012:5. http://ucfs.nek.uu.se/
[13] Bahl, R. (1984) Financing State and Local Government in the 1980s. Oxford University Press, New York.
[14] Ravn, M., Schmitt-Grohe, S. and Uribe, M. (2006) Deep Habits. Review of Economic Studies, 73, 195-218. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-937X.2006.00374.x
[15] Wellisch, D. and Hülshorst, J. (2000) A Second-Best Theory of Local Government Policy. International Tax and Public Finance, 7, 5-22. http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:1008749628237
[16] Casella, A. (2001) The Role of Market Size in the Formation of Jurisdictions. Review of Economic Studies, 68, 83-108. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1467-937X.00161
[17] Casella, A. and Feinstein, J.S. (2002) Public Goods in Trade: On the Formation of Markets and Jurisdictions. International Economic Review, 43, 437-462.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1468-2354.t01-1-00022
[18] Auffhammer, M. and Carson, R.T. (2009) Exploring the Number of First-Order Political Subdivisions across Countries: Some Stylized Facts. Journal of Regional Science, 49, 243-261.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9787.2008.00583.x
[19] Figuières, C. and Hindriks, J. (2001) Matching Grants and Ricardian Equivalence. Center for Operations Research and Econometrics (CORE) Discussion Paper No 2001048, Université catholique de Louvain, Louvain-la-Neuve.                                                   eww141208lx
[20] Hoyt, W. (2005) The Assignment and Division of the Tax Base in a System of Hierarchical Governments. Institute for Federalism and Intergovernmental Relations Working Paper No 2005-07, University of Kentucky, Lexington.

评论

此博客中的热门博文

A Comparison of Methods Used to Determine the Oleic/Linoleic Acid Ratio in Cultivated Peanut (Arachis hypogaea L.)

Cultivated peanut ( Arachis hypogaea L.) is an important oil and food crop. It is also a cheap source of protein, a good source of essential vitamins and minerals, and a component of many food products. The fatty acid composition of peanuts has become increasingly important with the realization that oleic acid content significantly affects the development of rancidity. And oil content of peanuts significantly affects flavor and shelf-life. Early generation screening of breeding lines for high oleic acid content greatly increases the efficiency of developing new peanut varieties. The objective of this study was to compare the accuracy of methods used to classify individual peanut seed as high oleic or not high oleic. Three hundred and seventy-four (374) seeds, spanning twenty-three (23) genotypes varying in oil composition (i.e. high oleic (H) or normal/not high oleic (NH) inclusive of all four peanut market-types (runner, Spanish, Valencia and Virginia), were individually tested ...

Location Optimization of a Coal Power Plant to Balance Costs against Plant’s Emission Exposure

Fuel and its delivery cost comprise the biggest expense in coal power plant operations. Delivery of electricity from generation to consumers requires investment in power lines and transmission grids. Placing a coal power plant or multiple power plants near dense population centers can lower transmission costs. If a coalmine is nearby, transportation costs can also be reduced. However, emissions from coal plants play a key role in worsening health crises in many countries. And coal upon combustion produces CO 2 , SO 2 , NO x , CO, Metallic and Particle Matter (PM10 & PM2.5). The presence of these chemical compounds in the atmosphere in close vicinity to humans, livestock, and agriculture carries detrimental health consequences. The goal of the research was to develop a methodology to minimize the public’s exposure to harmful emissions from coal power plants while maintaining minimal operational costs related to electric distribution losses and coal logistics. The objective was...

Evaluation of the Safety and Efficacy of Continuous Use of a Home-Use High-Frequency Facial Treatment Appliance

At present, many home-use beauty devices are available in the market. In particular, many products developed for facial treatment use light, e.g., a flash lamp or a light-emitting diode (LED). In this study, the safety of 4 weeks’ continuous use of NEWA TM , a high-frequency facial treatment appliance, every alternate day at home was verified, and its efficacy was evaluated in Japanese individuals with healthy skin aged 30 years or older who complained of sagging of the facial skin.  Transepidermal water loss (TEWL), melanin levels, erythema levels, sebum secretion levels, skin color changes and wrinkle improvement in the facial skin were measured before the appliance began to be used (study baseline), at 2 and 4 weeks after it had begun to be used, and at 2 weeks after completion of the 4-week treatment period (6 weeks from the study baseline). In addition, data obtained by subjective evaluation by the subjects themselves on a visual analog scale (VAS) were also analyzed. Fur...